Jean Monnet Center at NYU School of Law



Previous |Next |Title |Contents


Case Study One: Crated Calves and Trapped Turtles: Concluding Comments

This case study has examined the approach of the European Court and GATT panels to the single issue in the trade/environment debate which has most excited the wrath of environmentalists. This is concerned with the question of whether (and in what circumstances) states may introduce restrictions on trade which are predicated not upon the intrinsic environmental quality of the goods themselves, but upon their manner of production and the negative environmental consequences associated with this. This debate is often framed in the language of extra-territoriality because trade restrictions reflecting concerns about production processes are usually motivated by anxieties over environmental impact, not in the state imposing the restriction, but in the territory of the state from which the goods originate or (in the case of exports) for which they are destined. More often today this debate is conceived in terms of a distinction between product standards on the one hand, and process standards on the other. The latter conception is useful. Framed in these terms, the issue becomes one of the extent to which one state (State A) may restrict trade on the basis of the failure of a trading partner (State B) to comply with either its (State A's) domestic product standards or its (State A's) domestic process standards. This characterization sheds light upon the question of why this issue has proved more contentious in international law than in Community law. Indeed, as noted above, in Community law the issue has not yet been resolved.

Put simply (no doubt too simply), the premises underpinning these two legal orders have traditionally been distinct in terms of their approaches to trade in goods. Whereas Community law is predicated upon the concept of 'mutual recognition' of standards (subject to exceptions), the GATT rests upon a foundation of 'national treatment' (again subject to exceptions). Nonetheless, as seen above, the GATT effectively (de facto) departs from this principle of national treatment, in favour of mutual recognition, when it comes to the issue of the application of process standards. Hence the issue of process standards implies, in the context of the GATT, a de facto paradigm shift in terms of its foundational premise. While in certain respects Community law might treat product and process standards differently, the consequences of this are less pronounced in terms of the premises underlying the system.

There are, of course, other reasons as to why this issue has proved more contentious, and the debate more heated, in an international as opposed to a Community context. Most obviously, the Community's enhanced capacity for harmonization of standards, including those pertaining to production process, is of crucial practical and conceptual significance in easing the path from national treatment to mutual recognition. In areas such as environmental policy and social policy, mutual recognition of process standards in the Community operates against a backdrop of a shared regulatory framework constituted at Community level. Nonetheless economic ideology and the Community's 'legitimacy crisis' have combined to ensure that this framework is partial in its coverage and increasingly flexible in its scope.

It will be apparent that this debate about process standards is underpinned by a broad range of considerations; environmental, economic and moral. Central to it is the well-worn thesis that the capacity of states to regulate in areas such as the environment is contingent, in practice, upon their capacity to demand compliance with these standards on the part of their trading partners. The reasons for this are conceived as economic in nature. This thesis rests upon the assumption that social regulation, including environmental regulation, imposes costs upon economic actors and that economic actors will re-locate (or at least threaten to do so) where production can be more cheaply achieved in another state, without threatening market access. It is no longer only the wind which 'bloweth where it listeth'. This argument is captured by the concept of a regulatory race towards the bottom. [56] This thesis is less fashionable than it once was and certainly it has been applied, by some, in a manner which is excessively deterministic and insufficiently context specific. Nonetheless, it is a thesis which is hard to interrogate in empirical terms as it is difficult, if not impossible, to ascertain the extent to which social regulation is eschewed on the basis of competitiveness concerns. In the Community at least the need to harmonize conditions of competition continues to provide a (albeit contested) rationale for Community level regulation. [57]

While this debate has tended to be couched in the language of economics and the dangers associated with a de-regulatory 'competition between rules', the cases under discussion in this case study do not reflect exclusively, or arguably even principally, economic or competitiveness concerns. Rather, they bear testimony to the moral dimension of humankind's relationship with nature. In this, and in so far as they reflect the diversity of human values and of the norms giving expression to them, these cases pose a formidable challenge to international trade. The Dutch government's ban on the marketing of dead red grouse speaks not to economic realism but to an abhorrence of the practice of hunting wild birds for commercial gain. The Compassion in World Farming case arose against a backdrop of moral outrage as regards the functioning of the veal-crates system. A United Kingdom ban on the export of live calves would serve to prejudice rather than reinforce Britain's economic interests. For the United States the 'incidental' capture of sea turtles is conceived as an issue worthy of moral engagement, and no less so because the turtles concerned are 'foreign'.

In this, their moral dimension, the cases discussed above appear to be quite distinct from that to be examined in the second case study below. Here the trade restriction introduced is presented as having been predicated upon the physical impact of the imported goods on the health of consumers in the importing states. Nonetheless, in so far as physical impact is not established, this case also returns us to the theme of 'right' and 'wrong' in terms of production process, rather than 'good' or 'bad' in terms of physical impact. It is a theme to which we will return in the conclusion of this paper.




[56] See Poiares Maduro, M., We, the court: the European Court of Justice and the European Economic Constitution (Hart Publishing, 1997), chapter 4, for a discussion of the phenomenon of 'competition between rules'. Maduro cites much of the relevant literature pertaining to this debate. See also, for an excellent overview of this debate, and its empirical basis in a social policy context, Barnard, C., 'EC Social Poliy' in Craig, P. & de Burca, G., The Evolution of EU Law (OUP, forthcoming 1999).

[57] It is significant that even the Treaty of Amsterdam Protocol on the Application of the Principles of Subsidiarity and Proportionality recognizes this.


Previous |Next |Title |Contents

 

 

Top of the page